HomeGroupsTalkMoreZeitgeist
Search Site
This site uses cookies to deliver our services, improve performance, for analytics, and (if not signed in) for advertising. By using LibraryThing you acknowledge that you have read and understand our Terms of Service and Privacy Policy. Your use of the site and services is subject to these policies and terms.

Results from Google Books

Click on a thumbnail to go to Google Books.

Exit, Voice and Loyalty by Albert Hirschman
Loading...

Exit, Voice and Loyalty

by Albert Hirschman

MembersReviewsPopularityAverage ratingMentions
438456,970 (4.09)6
Hirshman's analysis of the role of exit and voice in institutional change is, I suspect, more referenced than read. There's a lot of not terribly good economics here, which lards up an already thin book. Nonetheless, the thematization is an useful one: and the lenses of Exit and Voice, are useful tools for thinking abotu how one people relate to institutions. Will the rise of complex economic goods led to a greater salience of "Voice" in market transactions? I would say LibraryThing itself is a vindication of that prediction! ( )
  ben_a | Aug 13, 2006 |
Showing 4 of 4
Hirschman majd 50 éves kötete arra vállalkozik, hogy nekimegy a klasszikus közgazdaságtan alaptételének (ami azóta már, gyanítom, nem annyira alaptétel), a „láthatatlan kéz” elméletének. Eszerint ugyanis a szabadversenyes kapitalizmus egyik tartópillére az, hogy ha egy vállalat termelékenysége csökken, akkor a vásárlók elpártolnak a cégtől (a szerző ezt nevezi kivonulásnak), ami a céget arra inspirálja, hogy javítson saját hatásfokán – és csiribú-csiribá, a szabadversenyes kapitalizmus máris regenerálta önmagát. Hirschman szerint azonban ez nincs így, mert 1.) ha a gyenge teljesítés általános (akár összejátszás folytán), akkor a kivonulók legfeljebb egy másik, ugyanolyan rosszul teljesítő céghez tudnak kivonulni, az meg halottnak a csók 2.) manapság szinte minden vállalatnak van kihasználatlan kapacitása („slack”), amiből esetleg el tudnak karistolni egy darabig még akkor is, ha jelentős számú vásárló hagyja faképnél őket 3.) itt vannak az úgynevezett „lusta monopóliumok” is, akik megelégednek azokkal a vásárlókkal, akik túl enerváltak, vagy egyenesen hülyék ahhoz, hogy alternatív szolgáltatásokkal váltsák le őket – mert Állam bácsi dotálja őket, úgyhogy igazából nem is szorulnak vásárlókra (igen, rád nézek, Magyar Posta, MÁV, meg a többi posztszoci szörnyszülött). Ebből következik, hogy a szimpla kivonulás nem elegendő visszacsatolás ahhoz, hogy üdvös változást idézzen elő – ám ahhoz, hogy kerek legyen a történet, Hirschmannak nem csak cáfolnia kell az elméletet, hanem új modellt is kénytelen alkotni*. Ennek érdekében bevezeti egyfelől a tiltakozás fogalmát, amelynek során a vásárlók nem otthagyják az adott vállalatot, hanem megmaradva vásárlónak, tiltakoznak a minőségromlás ellen. A szerző szerint ez az elem a kivonulással kiegészülve (lehetne) az igazi biztosítéka a szabadverseny öngyógyulásának – más kérdés, hogy a vásárlótól jóval több energiabefektetést igényel, mint a kivonulás. A harmadik fogalom pedig a hűség, ami akár racionális, akár irracionális (gondoljunk csak a magyar válogatott szurkolóira, nyehehe), Hirschman rendszerében meglehetősen pejoratív fogalom, mert lehetővé teszi, hogy a vállalatok megmaradjanak rossz beidegződéseiknél. Ezeknek a fogalmaknak a kombinációjával pedig már nagyon szép új modellt lehet alkotni.

Persze szép, vagy nem szép, el nem olvastam volna, ha csupán a közgazdaságra vonatkozna. De Hirschman rendszerében az a nagyszerű, hogy kábé mindenre rá lehet húzni – a pártpolitikai változásokra, az oktatásra, sőt: az Egyesült Államok egész történelmére is**. A kivonulás és a tiltakozás ezeknek a rendszereknek az öngyógyításában is elengedhetetlen, elég a totalitárius rezsimekre gondolni, amelyek lehetetlenné teszik őket, és ezzel rendesen el is veszítik sanszukat a megújulásra. Ez a sokszólamúság, és Hirschman széleskörű közgazdasági, pszichológiai és politológiai tudása az, amitől ez a rövid kötet olyan fontossá válik – annyira fontossá, hogy 1984-ben még a magyar Művelődési Minisztérium is kénytelen volt lefordítani. Azzal együtt, hogy a közgazdaságtan azóta már bizonyára számos változáson ment keresztül, kifejezetten inspiráló, nehéz, de velős szövegnek éreztem.

Update 2019: És arra kellett rájönnöm, hogy a közösségi oldalak esetében is tökéletesen megállja a helyét mindaz, amit Hirschman állít. Ha ugyanis egy oldal a tiltakozás lehetőségét szimplán technikai eszközökkel a felületen kívülre szorítja, akkor a kivonulás és hűség kettőse önmagában sosem lesz képes feloldani a működési anomáliákat. Mert egyedül a tiltakozás, a pozitív értelemben vett tiltakozás az, ami visszacsatolást jelent a működtető részére a problémákról - persze ha a működtetőt nem érdeklik a problémák, látni sem akarja őket, az már az ő baja. Mert a problémák attól még ott lesznek.

* "…egy modellt sohasem a tények – bármekkora cáfolóerejük van ezeknek egyébként –, hanem mindig csak egy másik modell hatására vetnek el a tudósok.” (a Streeten-Kuhn maxima)
** Hisz az USA születése is egy gigantikus kivonulás eredménye: az európai „szolgáltatásokkal” elégedetlen kivonulók alapították, és az egész Vadnyugat-mítosz is a kivonulás mítosza – hogy a pionír, ha nem találja a helyét keleten, elmehet a messzi nyugatra, a szűzföldekre, hogy a két kezével teremtsen magának szerencsét. ( )
  Kuszma | Jul 2, 2022 |
A rare book that is both insightful and less than two hundred pages. I miss the days when "serious" books got by their content and not by their length. Originally recommended to me by a freshman year professor, Exit, Voice and Loyalty is a classic for a good reason. I was recently reminded of it when in Con Law. Exit, voice and loyalty made a surprise appearance in Bruce Ackerman's article about the role of exit and Carolene Products footnote 4 (if "exit" from unpopular minorities is too easy, it makes it difficult organize activism. While it seems like it would be a disadvantage to be clearly identifiable as a minority, the ability to "cover" comes with its own problems). Some of the examples and politics are a bit outdated, and Hirshman clearly has his political sympathies (Ralph Nader gets a few honorable mentions, as does Eugene McCarthy), but this book is worth reading for the timeless principles Hirshman articulates as well as the breadth and creativity that he brings to economics.

The basic idea of the book is that there are two major responses to declines in firms or organizations. The first is exit, "vote with your feet" to stop buying the product or to quit the organization. The second is voice, to raise a ruckus by protest. Hirshman notes that economists tend to think of exit as the exclusive response, while political scientists tend to focus on the voice mechanism.

In Hirshman's model, firms face random quality deterioration that is correctable if management responds to either exit or voice. Hirshman makes the interesting note that for management to respond and correct, exit cannot be too fast or too slow, since aggressive exit would lead to the collapse of the firm before response. Exit also fails to correct firm decline, if the consumer just aimlessly cycles through what are substantially the same firms (some radicals argue that political parties allow the status quo through exactly this mechanism. Voters unhappy with one party exit it and switch to another, only to be disappointed and so-on, when in fact the problem is the system itself).

Voice can be a residual to exit, in some situations (such as monopoly or in autocracies) it may be possible that exit is impossible, and voice is the only response. Voice can also be a substitute to exit, consumers may protest before they stop buying a product. Voice is also more complicated in that members of an organization and consumers must consider the chance that their voice will be effective, and the worthwhileness of a correction compared to the certainty of another existing product. For that reason, organizational memberships and major purchases are likely to be places where voice is used as a substitute to exit.

The most interesting parts of the book come from the interactions between exit and voice. A special difficulty is that the consumers that are most quality conscious (consumers probably face different utilities from different quality levels, making it impossible to translate quality to effective price decreases) and thus in the best position to exercise voice to alert management to failure are also the most likely to exit in response to a decline in quality, leaving the firm to continue to decline. The examples that Hirshman uses are interesting, from Nigerian railroads (they were bad at the time because being publicly funded, management was not sensitive to exit, and the alternatives of cars allow quality sensitive consumers to exit the railroad), to shareholders who quickly sell instead of protesting to management (no longer strictly true, with the rise of activist shareholders. In a sense Hirshman anticipates this, as he mentions that there may be ways to make the voice mechanism more successful/less costly). Hirshman even argues that in some cases, monopolies want to create an exit option to rid itself of troublesome protestors, thereby making even competition a tool of monopolies. A fascinating chapter is Hirshman's answer to the failure of the medium voter theorem. The medium voter theorem predicts that all political parties move towards the center in order to maximize the number of voters. Hirshman notes the failure of this model when political parties consistently produce extreme candidates. Hirshman's answer is that the party may not be responsive to edge voters who exit the party if the party moves on the idealogical spectrum, but more responsive to the "captive" members of the party who voice. These captive members tend to be ideologues who want "purer" candidates.

There is a lengthy chapter on loyalty that explores some interesting ideas as well. Hirshman mentions that loyalty may be useful because it slows the exit of members and consumers, giving firms a chance to correct their decline. Loyalty many case consumers/members to be less sensitive to initial decline but more willing to use voice than others past a certain threshold. A loyalist's threat to exit is a combination of voice and exit, and organizations that make it impossible to threaten exit (that penalize threats of exit with death for example) collapse quickly. Finally, Hirshman discusses situations where loyalists cannot truly exit the organization, therefore turning their decision to exit into balance of the shame of staying in an organization and the chance of reforming "from the inside".

The chapter on applying the concepts to American politics is a little dated but still thoughtful. Hirshman notes that the US is a country formed out of those who "exited" other societies. One of the most thought provoking arguments in this chapter was that high achieving minorities tended to exit their cultural group, depriving that group of those most able to use voice to protest the injustices towards that minority. Hirshman notes in the book, that was the reason that political movements had been focusing on group upward mobility rather than individual upward mobility.

Hirshman ends the book with the note that organizations may have varying responses to exit and voice. That leads to the simple conclusion that to fix much decline, steps should be taken to either make the organization more sensitive to existing voice or exit or make it easier for voice/exit to come out. However, there might not be a stable optimal mix of voice/exit because those mechanisms are also subject to decline (Hirshman gives the example of LBJ administration institutionalizing dissent, keeping major players from resigning and affecting policy by allowing them to "air their conscience").

In short, highly recommended reading.
( )
  vhl219 | Jun 1, 2019 |
Eliot Spitzer said: "But the participation of shareholders is genuinely difficult. The problem starts with the remarkable liquidity in the stock market. Owners of shares can trade out and sell their positions easily. Isn’t that a good thing? Of course. But it also means that shareholders do not stay in for the long, hard slog of reforming companies in which they have a momentary ownership interest. Liquidity thus undermines the urgency of and the argument for participation.

Albert O. Hirschman’s 1970 book, Exit, Voice, and Loyalty, brilliantly captures this dynamic. How do people consider the various options they face when they see a product—whether toothpaste, a political party, or a share in a company—and need to decide whether to use their voice to improve it or to exit and find something better? Hirschman presciently observed the implications of easy exit options for “perpetuating bad management”: because of the “ready availability of alternative investment opportunities in the stock market . . . any resort to voice rather than to exit is unthinkable for any but the most committed stockholder.” Somehow we have to overcome this problem. Perhaps shareholders should be given additional voting power if they own a stock longer. That solution has its own troubles. But we need to find a way to give shareholders the power and incentive to get involved."
  pedestrian | Mar 20, 2010 |
Hirshman's analysis of the role of exit and voice in institutional change is, I suspect, more referenced than read. There's a lot of not terribly good economics here, which lards up an already thin book. Nonetheless, the thematization is an useful one: and the lenses of Exit and Voice, are useful tools for thinking abotu how one people relate to institutions. Will the rise of complex economic goods led to a greater salience of "Voice" in market transactions? I would say LibraryThing itself is a vindication of that prediction! ( )
  ben_a | Aug 13, 2006 |
Showing 4 of 4

Current Discussions

None

Popular covers

Quick Links

Rating

Average: (4.09)
0.5
1
1.5
2 1
2.5 3
3 5
3.5 2
4 11
4.5
5 16

Is this you?

Become a LibraryThing Author.

 

About | Contact | Privacy/Terms | Help/FAQs | Blog | Store | APIs | TinyCat | Legacy Libraries | Early Reviewers | Common Knowledge | 204,517,967 books! | Top bar: Always visible